Introduction
When
Anwar Sadat became Egypt’s president in 1970 following the death of his
predecessor Gamal Abdel Nasser, he set in motion radical changes in economic
policy known commonly as al-Infitah in Arabic, which means “the opening” in
English, moving the country away from import-substitution policies and towards
a free market system that involved greater interconnection with the global
economy.[1] This shift also had political implications as
it moved the country away from the Soviet Union and towards the United
States. Sadat’s successor Hosni Mubarak,
pressured by the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and other international
institutions in the midst of a debt crisis, continued the trend of neoliberal
structural readjustment from the late 1980’s to the 2000’s with mixed results.[2] The country experienced significant GDP
growth but a growing gap between rich and poor as well, creating some of the
structural conditions that led to the 2011 revolution. The changes that took place in Egypt were not
unique. Many other countries throughout
the Middle East and the developing world in general experienced similar liberal
economic and political shifts throughout this time period with varying degrees
of success and failure.[3] Why
did this happen and what were the consequences of al-Infitah?
Given
that the issue in question transcends national borders and involves the
interaction of multiple states, it is best to approach it from an
international-relations (IR) perspective.
There are several IR ontological theories that can help explain the
spread of neoliberal economic reforms throughout the globe in the last forty
years and in Egypt specifically. These
theories are as follows: (1) neo-realism, (2) neo-liberalism, and (3) economic
structuralism. Although each of these
theories can help explain various aspects of what happened in Egypt and
elsewhere in the developing world over the last four decades, by themselves,
they can’t explain the full phenomenon.
To understand al-Infitah, neo-realists could analyze changes in Cold War
power politics, which include the decline and collapse of the Soviet Union and
the rise of a uni-polar world led by the United States. Neo-liberals
could focus on the greater potential for peaceful cooperation between states
created by advancements in communication and transportation technology as well
the rise of international institutions like the IMF and the World Bank. Finally, economic structuralists could analyze
the oil shocks of the 1970’s, growing third world debt, and the developing
world’s economic dependency on the West.
Each theory on its own fails to explain the full dynamics of al-Infitah;
only when analyzing it from the perspective of all three IR ontological
theories does a fuller picture begin to emerge.
Neo-Realism
Did
Anwar Sadat and other political leaders in the developing world open up their
economies beginning in the 1970’s in response to the decline of the Soviet
Union and the growing hegemonic dominance of the United States? Although there are some shortcomings to this
theory as it neglects Egypt’s domestic dynamics and it underestimates the
potential for states to gain collectively from cooperation, it is impossible to
ignore the influence of Western military power on Egyptian politics over the
last six decades.
To understand the Infitah
from a realist perspective, it is necessary to look at the independence movements
in the developing world that took place in the aftermath of WWII. Throughout the 1950’s and 1960’s, Egypt,
Tunisia, Algeria, Syria, Iraq, and Libya witnessed the rise of anti-Western political
movements. This led to a series of
revolutions, civil wars, and coup d’états that brought a new generation of
leaders to power.[4] Distrustful of European countries due to decades
of colonial subjugation, Arab dictators like Abdel Nasser in Egypt called for
the unification of the Arab world to defend their collective interests. This foreign policy became known as Arab
Nationalism, and it resulted in ill-fated unions between Egypt and Syria from
1958 to 1961, and Egypt and Yemen between 1962 and 1967. It also led to a protracted conflict between
Arab states and Israel. Part of the Arab
Nationalist platform was to close off the economy from Western manufactured
goods in order to develop an industrial sector backed by the wealth and power
of the state. From the Arab Nationalist
perspective, only through industrialization and militarization could the Arab
world defend its interests.
Arab nationalist movements
might not have been possible without the military support provided by the
Soviet Union and its satellites in Eastern Europe, who supplied weapons and aid
to Arab Nationalist regimes throughout the 1950’s and 1960’s to help them oppose
the West.[5] Meanwhile, the United States gave arms to its
allies in the Arab Gulf, Turkey, Iran, and Israel during the same time period
to counteract the influence of the U.S.S.R.
Like in the rest of the world, the Soviet Union and the United States
used military and economic aid as a way to strengthen alliances in the region
in their struggle for hegemonic domination.
However, the balance of power
would not last forever. By the late
1960’s, the United States was beginning to outpace the Soviet Union in terms of
technological capacity, economic growth, and human development. America’s allies throughout the developing
world were clearly benefiting from the superior technology provided by the
superpower. In 1967, the tiny state of
Israel won a shocking victory against Egypt, Syria, and Jordan in a war that
lasted only six days and displayed quite clearly the military superiority of
the West.[6] Israel occupied the Sinai Peninsula in Egypt,
the Golan Heights in Syria, and all of Palestine’s territory by the end of the
war. Although Abdel Nasser would stay in
power another three years, his Arab Nationalist project had collapsed.
Nasser’s successor Anwar
Sadat saw the writing on the wall. With
the Soviet Union clearly on the decline and Israel occupying part of Egypt’s
territory, Sadat spent the next decade reversing the country’s foreign policy. After
several years of negotiations, he formally agreed to a peace treaty with Israel
in 1978 at the Camp David Accords. In
exchange for recognizing the state of Israel and keeping the Suez Canal open to
the international community, Egypt received the Sinai Peninsula back and approximately
two billion dollars in annual American aid, 1.3 billion of which would go to
the Egyptian military.[7] America now provides training for Egyptian
officers and some advanced military technology—not too advanced of course—in
exchange for loyalty. American power
only continued to grow in the region in the years following the collapse of the
Soviet Union in 1991.
Over this time period, Arab
states may have engaged in economic structural reforms to appease Western
government officials and international institutions promoting the Washington
Consensus.[8] The neoliberal reform packages proposed by
the United States and the IMF often included recommendations to liberalize
trade, reduce government spending, strengthen the rule of law, increase
government transparency, and open up the political system to competitive
elections. Problems with national debt were not the only
reason why developing countries attempted to make some of these reforms. Complying with Western powers on these issues
often meant greater access to military aid.
A neorealist can argue that
Arab states had no interest in making substantial changes to the structure of the
economy or the political system but were pressured by Western political
institutions to do so. Indeed, Arab
dictators often resisted the full implementation of liberal reforms, fearful
that making real structural changes to the political system or the economy
would lead to losing support from various sectors of society and control over
the political system.[9]
What resulted was arguably the illusion
of reform.
For example, Anwar Sadat
created a new constitution in 1971 and held parliamentary elections in 1977 for
the first time since the pre-Nasser era, and his successor Hosni Mubarak held
the first presidential elections with multiple candidates in 2005.[10] However, elections in Egypt under Sadat and
Mubarak were mockeries of the democratic process as the country’s ruling National
Democratic Party (NDP) fixed the results of every contest to their benefit. Elections served as a means to co-opt wealthy
businessmen and moderate reformers into the NDP while presenting a false image
of democratic legitimacy to the outside world.
Civil liberties were heavily
restricted, which prevented oppositional parties from spreading their message
and mobilizing voters. The same process
of illiberal democratic reforms took place in most other countries in the
Middle East.
It can also be argued that liberal
economic reforms implemented by Middle Eastern regimes were highly misleading. It is true that Egypt denationalized over
half of its state owned industries from the 1970’s to the 1990’s. By the year 2000, approximately 76 percent of
all state-owned industry had been privatized.[11] It is also true that tariffs were reduced
from 42.2 percent of all goods in 1990 to 16.7 percent in 2007, and quotas were
eliminated by the beginning of the 2000’s in compliance with the standards of
the World Trade Organization. Free trade
zones were created and foreign direct investment increased substantially. However, most privatized industries in Egypt
fell into the hands of crony capitalists with connections to the regime. They received special perks from the state
that included subsidies; special access to licenses and government contracts;
and protection from foreign imports through non-tariff barriers. Although industrial production did increase substantially
as a total percentage of GDP in the 1990’s, the percent of industrial exports
as a total percentage of foreign trade only increased from 25 to 33
percent. Egypt’s industrial sector
remained uncompetitive internationally and highly protected by the state. Al-Infitah witnessed the reduced role of the
state in society and more foreign trade, but it also saw the creation of a new
political faction of crony capitalists by the 1990’s with ties to powerful
members of Mubarak’s government. A similar scenario can be found in other Arab
states that made al-Infitah reforms. From
this perspective, “the opening” was only a partial one to appease the West.
A realist can also argue that
the United States prioritized power politics over economic and democratic reforms
as well. Although the United States has
placed pressure on Middle Eastern regimes to make liberal reforms, they have
often backed down on these demands to prevent the loss of a strategic ally in the region or if they needed the
political support of an Arab state in the midst of a crisis. For example, when the revolution took place
in Egypt at the beginning of 2011, the United States initially supported a
peaceful democratic transition, and they also condemned the Egyptian military when
they overthrew the democratically elected government of Mohamed Morsi on July
3, 2013.[12] However, after only a brief period of
suspending military aid, the United States restored its support to Egypt’s
military junta because they needed a strong ally to help stop the spread of radical
Islamist groups like ISIS as well as weaken Iran’s proxy allies in the Gaza
Strip and Yemen. One can argue that the United States only pressures
countries to implement liberal reforms when it doesn’t involve sacrificing
their primary political interests.
However,
the neo-realist image of an anarchic world of states competing in a zero-sum game
fails to explain the full dynamics of al-Infitah. Although it is easy to find a link between
American military pressure and Egypt’s liberal reforms beginning in the 1970’s,
it is much harder to make that same conclusion with Tunisia, a country that was
not pressured militarily at all by the United States but still engaged in liberal
structural reforms beginning in 1969.[13] It is possible that power politics is not the
only factor that influences relations between states. Furthermore, both Egypt and the United States
arguably made considerable gains from their cooperation throughout “the opening.” The neo-realist view of a world dominated by
a zero-sum game cannot make sense of this.
Neo-Liberalism
A neo-liberal would understand
al-Infitah as being more than a product of American political hegemony. They would also see it as a consequence of the
development of new communications and transport technology; the spread of
democratic norms; and the proliferation of international institutions that
coordinate activity between states.[14] These factors help explain why most countries
throughout the world—even ones not directly influenced by the United States’
military—began integrating their economies into the global market place and
adopting Western political norms. The
end result for most countries throughout the globe was a significant rise in
GDP, life expectancy, and the average standard of living.[15]
A neoliberal would have a
different interpretation of international relations during the 1950’s and
1960’s than their neorealist counterparts. For example, when Israel, France, and Great
Britain made the fateful decision to invade the Suez Canal in 1956, they may
have done so according to a neo-liberal because they were living in an age when
news traveled slower, international institutions were weaker, and distrust
between nations was much higher in comparison with today.[16] Although the technology of the era allowed
for greater interconnection within states and the fostering of nationalist
movements, most countries were still poorly connected with the global
economy. As a result, chauvinistic
nationalist movements and powerful states that had a heavy hand in the economy
were the norm throughout the middle of the twentieth century. These were the same political forces that led
to the devastation created by European imperialism, the World Wars, and the
proxy conflicts of the Cold War. This distrust between nations led to an
international game dominated by power politics.
However, by the late 1960’s
and 1970’s, great advances in communications and travel arguably began to
change the nature of relations between states and nations. The rise of cheap air travel allowed
businesses and non-governmental organizations to take their activities overseas
to the remote corners of the planet. As
a result, thousands of NGO’s were established in Egypt by the 1990’s with the
help of Western aid. Furthermore, the spread
of satellites, cell phones, and the internet in the following decades made
communication across borders instantaneous.
From 2000 to 2011, the amount of internet users increased by 3,458
percent throughout the Middle East, and over 1,100 satellite channels were
available by 2012 in the region.[17]
Western values and norms began spreading
across the globe as a result. Also, international
institutions were able to use new communication, transportation, and
statistical tools to increase cooperation between states. With assistance from international
organizations like the IMF and the WTO, most countries throughout the globe
made structural reforms to interconnect themselves with the global
economy.
Under these changing
international conditions from the 1970’s to the present, the IMF and the World
Bank played a fundamental role in coordinating activity between international
banks and countries like Egypt to solve debt and developmental problems.[18] Both the Sadat and Mubarak regimes faced
numerous balance of payments crises due to growing populations, economically
unproductive state industries, unstable oil prices, and over bloated
bureaucracies. International
institutions like the IMF were able to help Egypt restructure its economy and
create greater macro-economic stability by providing their knowledge and
expertise.[19] When Mubarak negotiated with the IMF in the
late 1980’s and early 1990’s, he was able to obtain a deal where half of the
country’s debt would be forgiven by international banks in exchange for instituting
long term structural reforms, which included making cuts to government spending. Although the neoliberal economic reforms
were often inconsistent and crony capitalists dominated the process, Egypt did
avoid an economic collapse. Furthermore,
the country was able to import new technology in the fields of communication,
medicine, education, and transportation, which improved the life expectancy and
standard of living of the average Egyptian. The average Egyptian’s life expectancy
increased from fifty three years in 1970 to seventy years in 2005.[20]
In addition, Egypt’s economy grew at an
average rate of approximately five percent per year between 1990 and 2008.[21] In turn, America gained a new ally in the
region, and Western investors found a new market to invest their surplus
capital. The neoliberal perspective of
al-Infitah shows how both the West and Egypt were able to gain mutually from
their interaction. International
relations are not always a zero sum game.
These changing global
dynamics may also have played a role in Egypt’s internal political reforms. Although the activities of Islamist and
liberal opposition groups were limited by the government and elections were
fixed, the regimes of Sadat and Mubarak at various points in time gave more
space for the political opposition to establish non-governmental organizations
and even allowed some limited criticism of the state.[22] Overtime, it became increasingly difficult
for the government to clamp down on political dissent. A neo-liberal would argue that the 2011
revolution was a result of the spread of mass communication technology like the
internet, cell phones, and social networking as well as the influence of
non-governmental organizations and Western governments on the country.
However, there are some aspects
of the Infitah for which neo-liberal theory can’t account. For one, it can’t tell us why Syria and Iran
did not engage in a similar economic or political opening. Neo-realists can explain this by analyzing
the role power politics played in the region; specifically, the current
conflict between Iran and the United States over political dominance in the
region, which involves economic sanctions on the Iranian regime due to its
nuclear program. Furthermore, neither of
the neo-schools can explain why the wealth gap grew between rich and poor in
Egypt as well as the rest of the globe between 1970 and 2011.
Economic Structuralism
Economic
structuralists argue that both the neo-realist and neo-liberals can’t explain
why al-Infitah led to an increase in the wealth gap between rich and poor over
the last forty years.[23] They would also argue that the neo schools underemphasize
the role that international institutions like the IMF and multi-national
companies play in international relations.
Lastly, economic structuralists see economics, not political power, as
the most important factor affecting international relations. According to economic structuralists, the state
is nothing more than an apparatus by which the wealthy elite protect their
economic interests. To explain al-Infitah,
economic structuralists would focus on how the oil crisis of the 1970’s and the
growing debt of third world governments led desperate leaders of developing
countries to make deals with the IMF to restructure their economies.[24]
Naturally,
economic structuralists would analyze the Arab Nationalist regimes of the post
colonial era from an economic standpoint.
In the 1950’s and 1960’s, Egypt’s political leadership attempted to end
the country’s dependency on the West.
The country’s economy throughout the colonial era from 1882 to 1952 had
been dependent on exporting cotton to Europe in exchange for manufactured goods.[25] While Egypt’s aristocracy had grown wealthy
from the export of cotton to Europe, the great majority of people were mired in
poverty and illiteracy, living as peasants in villages. When Abdel Nasser and other Arab Nationalist
dictators came to power, they realized that the only way to create economic
growth and modernize the country was through industrialization. Since the population lacked the skills and
the capital necessary to establish and run competitive factories, the state
took on the responsibility of development by investing in manufacturing. By the early 1950’s, Abdel Nasser had
nationalized most of the countries businesses and placed high tariffs on goods
to protect the state’s factories from outside competition. These economic policies are known as import
substitution industrialization (ISI). Furthermore,
to increase the average standard of living, the Egyptian state spent extensive
amounts of money on providing welfare, education and jobs in the
bureaucracies. Large infrastructure
projects like the High Dam at Aswan and public housing units in Cairo were
constructed. To pay for it, the
government took out loans from banks abroad and accepted financial assistance
from the Soviet Union. The hope was that
the investment would pay off in the future.
However,
ISI had many problems as corruption in the bureaucracy led to inefficient
industrial production. Furthermore,
growing populations, soaring costs of welfare, and the war in Yemen from 1962
to 1967 put a strain on the state budget.[26]
Establishing a welfare state before
industrializing often leads to problems with debt. Lastly, by cutting themselves off from the
West, they lost access to potential markets to which they could export their
goods and import new technology. By the
late 1960’s, the Egyptian state found itself heavily in debt. To
make matters worse, oil prices world-wide increased dramatically in the early
1970’s as a result of the formation of the oil cartel OPEC and the oil embargo
that took place during the 1973 war.
Desperate for capital, Nasser’s successor Anwar Sadat, like many other heads
of state in developing countries throughout the world, had to make economic
reforms.
The
best place countries could turn to for more capital was international
banks. However, economic institutions
would not give out loans to financially unstable countries unless they made and
fulfilled promises to restructure government spending. Economic
structuralists point out the critical role played by international institutions
that represent the global capitalist class in pressuring third world
governments to make neoliberal reforms.
From the neo-Marxist perspective, organizations like the IMF were not only
interested in helping third world states balance their budgets through the cutting
of government spending. They were also interested
in opening up the economies of developing countries so that Western businesses
could find new markets for their products and new locations to establish their
factories.[27] The oil shocks of the 1970’s had hurt the
profit margins of factory and business owners in Western countries, and many
corporations and banks were looking for markets with cheaper labor and
potential consumers. Desperate to save
their regimes from economic ruin, regimes like that of Sadat and Mubarak were
willing to restructure their political-economy.
Although
al-Infitah reforms in the Middle East did allow for increased access to loans
and foreign direct investment, it also created an enormous gap between rich and
poor.[28] To cut spending, states inflated the currency
and cut the salaries of government workers, driving hundreds of thousands into
poverty. Government services in
education and health care declined considerably. Furthermore, government subsidies on food stuffs
were either cut or substantially reduced.
Jobs were cut as new agricultural technology forced peasants off their
land and new industrial technology created layoffs in manufacturing. The youth were hurt the worst by these
reforms as many bureaucracies chose to make spending cuts by not hiring new
workers, leaving many college graduates unemployed. The reforms created political conflicts
between rich and poor as best exemplified in Egypt by the 1977 bread riots and
the 2006 labor strikes by workers in the textile mills in the city of Mahalla
in central Egypt. Desperate for help, the poor turned to private
charity networks funded by Islamist groups like the Muslim Brotherhood. A small percentage of the youth were
radicalized, joining Islamist organizations like al-Jihad that practiced
political violence against the state. Desperate
for work, many of Egypt’s poor fled to work either in the West or in the Arab
Gulf. Meanwhile, the rich fled to wealthy
suburbs like the Sixth of October and New Cairo to escape the deteriorating
inner cities of Cairo and Alexandria.
These economic structural problems in Egypt and other Middle Easter
countries were arguably the basis for the 2011 revolution.
Egypt's al-Infitah reforms also led to greater economic dependency on the West. In the late 1970's, significant oil deposits were discovered and exploited in Egypt with the help of Western companies. By 1980, approximately thirty percent of Egypt's GDP and the majority of the country's exports were dependent on fossil fuel exports. Along with oil, other rents like transportation fees from the Suez Canal, remittances from workers living in the Gulf, and partial rents like foreign aid and tourism were providing the Egyptian state with over two thirds of the government's revenue. Although the government initially used this wealth to prop up the country's over bloated bureaucracy, inefficient state-protected industries, and expansive welfare state, the country's revenue from oil rents would gradually decline from 30 percent in 1980 to 8 percent of GDP in 2010 due to population growth, increased domestic demand for energy, and decreasing supplies. Instead of responding to this problem by promoting economic development, free markets, and industrial exports, Egypt's government instead cut spending as requested by the IMF in the late 1980's and 1990's. While many crony capitalists in fields such as fossil fuels, mineral resources, tourism, and telecommunications have grown wealthier as a result of Western dependency, the majority of the population has seen their welfare benefits cut, their educational systems decline, and their access to government jobs pulled out from under their feet. Economic structuralists often point out that the Middle East's dependence on oil exports is holding back the region's development.
Egypt's al-Infitah reforms also led to greater economic dependency on the West. In the late 1970's, significant oil deposits were discovered and exploited in Egypt with the help of Western companies. By 1980, approximately thirty percent of Egypt's GDP and the majority of the country's exports were dependent on fossil fuel exports. Along with oil, other rents like transportation fees from the Suez Canal, remittances from workers living in the Gulf, and partial rents like foreign aid and tourism were providing the Egyptian state with over two thirds of the government's revenue. Although the government initially used this wealth to prop up the country's over bloated bureaucracy, inefficient state-protected industries, and expansive welfare state, the country's revenue from oil rents would gradually decline from 30 percent in 1980 to 8 percent of GDP in 2010 due to population growth, increased domestic demand for energy, and decreasing supplies. Instead of responding to this problem by promoting economic development, free markets, and industrial exports, Egypt's government instead cut spending as requested by the IMF in the late 1980's and 1990's. While many crony capitalists in fields such as fossil fuels, mineral resources, tourism, and telecommunications have grown wealthier as a result of Western dependency, the majority of the population has seen their welfare benefits cut, their educational systems decline, and their access to government jobs pulled out from under their feet. Economic structuralists often point out that the Middle East's dependence on oil exports is holding back the region's development.
Of
course, this theory fails to explain all aspects of al-Infitah. For one, not all countries in the Middle East
had the same degree of economic inequality or industrial exports. IMF reforms in Turkey produced far more
favorable results in terms of increasing industrial exports and improving the
quality of life for the average person.[29]
Political explanations like the quality of Turkey’s bureaucracy help explain
this. Also, economic structural theories
claim that liberal IMF reforms made states throughout the globe more dependent
on Western industrial goods, which in turn increased the amount of inequality
throughout the globe. However, Egypt’s
industrial production increased as a percentage of GDP over the last forty
years due to non-tariff protections of locally produced goods. Furthermore, countries like South Korea and
Turkey were able to gradually implement neo-liberal reforms while helping their
industrial sector prepare for international competition. Deindustrialization is not always a
consequence of neoliberal reforms.
Conclusion
Although
each IR ontological theory provides a unique perspective on al-Infitah in Egypt
and the rest of the developing world, each perspective cannot explain the full
phenomenon. Furthermore, there are other
IR theories like Social Constructivism, Post-Colonialism, and Critical Theory that
could shed further light on the causes of al-Infitah and its consequences for
the Middle East and the world in general.
The idea encompasses too many political, social, and economic issues to
be understood under one general theory.
In
conclusion, there are several things to take from this analysis. First, al-Infitah in Egypt was mainly the
result of the following factors: 1) the decline of the Soviet Union and the
emergence of the United States as the sole superpower; 2) the growth of new
technologies and international institutions associated with globalization in
the late 1960’s and 1970’s; and 3) the balance of payments crisis as a result
of the failures of ISI policies and the oil shocks of the 1970’s. Second, al-Infitah had the following consequences
for Egypt: 1) the partial liberalization
of the economic and political system that included illiberal democratic reforms
and the rise of a crony capitalist class; 2) the increase in international
trade and the importation of new technology; 3) the increase of GDP and average
living standards coupled with a growing gap in wealth between rich and poor; and
4) the creation of some of the long term political, economic, and social
conditions that led to the Egyptian revolution in 2011.
Work Cited
1. Adly, Amr.
State Reform and Development in the Middle East: Turkey and Egypt in
the Post- Liberalization Era.
Rutledge: London, 2013.
2. Deudney, Daniel and G. John Ikenberry. "The Nature and Sources of International
Liberal Order," Review of International Studies, 25, 1999: 179-96.
3. Gause, Gregory. “Systematic Approaches to Middle East
International Relations,” International Studies Review, 1(1), Spring,
1999: 11-31.
4. Heydemann, Steven. 2014. “America’s Response
to the Arab Uprisings: US Foreign Assistance in an Era of Ambivalence,” Mediterranean
Politics Vol. 19, 3: 299-317.
5. Kadhim, Abbas, ed. Governance in the Middle East and North
Africa. Rutledge: London, 2013.
6. Kauppi, M. and P. Viotti. “Economic Structuralism: Global Capitalism and
Postcolonialism,” VK, 2012: 187-207.
7. Khatib, Lina. “Transforming the Media: From Tool of the
Rulers to Tool of Empowerment,” in Arab Human Development in the Twenty-First
Century: The Primacy of Empowerment, ed. Bahgat Korany. The American University in Cairo Press: Cairo,
2014.
7. King, Stephen. Liberalization Against Democracy. Indiana University Press: Indian, 2003.
8. Lamy. S.L. “Contemporary Mainstream
Approaches: Neo-Realism and NeoLiberalism,” BSO, 2011: 114-129.
9. Lipson, Charles. “The International Organization of Third
World Debt,” in Towards a Political Economy of Development: A Rational Choice
Perspective, Edited by Robert Bates.
University of California Press: Los Angeles, 1988, pg 12-46.
9. Niblock, Tim and Emma Murphy, eds. Economic and Political Liberalization in
the Middle East. British Academic Press: London, 1993.
10. Ould-Mey, Mohameden. "Structural Adjustment Programs and
Democratization in Africa," pg 35-66 in Multiparty Democracy and
Political Change: Constraints to Democratization in Africa. Edited by John Mukum Mbaku and Julius
Omozuanvbo Ihonvbere. Africa World
Press: New Jersey, 2006.
11. Owen, Roger. State, Power, and Politics in the Making
of the Modern Middle East. Rutledge:
London, 2004.
12. Richards, Alan, John Waterbury, Melani
Cammett, and Ishac Diwan. A Political
Economy of the Middle East, third edition.
West View Press: United States, 2014.
13. Sayyid, Mustaph. "International Dimensions of Middle
Eastern Authoritarianism," pg 215-230 in Debating Arab Authoritarianism:
Dynamics and Durability in Nondemocratic Regimes. Edited by Oliver
Schlumberger. Stanford University
Press: Stanford, 2007.
[1]
Richards, Alan, John Waterbury, Melani Cammett and Ishac Diwan. A Political Economy of the Middle East,
pg 27.
[2]
Adly,
Amr. State Reform and Development in
the Middle East: Turkey and Egypt in the Post- Liberalization Era. Rutledge: London, 2013, 70-115.
[3]
Lipson, Charles. “The International
Organization of Third World Debt,” in Towards a Political Economy of
Development: A Rational Choice Perspective, Edited by Robert Bates. University of California Press: Los Angeles,
1988, pg 12-46.
[4]
Owen,
Roger. State, Power, and Politics in
the Making of the Modern Middle East.
Rutledge: London, 2004, pg 19-29.
[5]
Gause,
Gregory. “Systematic Approaches to
Middle East International Relations,” International Studies Review,
1(1), Spring, 1999: 11-31.
[6]
Owen, Ibid.
[7]
Richards,
Alan, John Waterbury, Melani Cammett, and Ishac Diwan. A Political Economy of the Middle East,
third edition. West View Press:
United States, 2014, 344-361.
[8]
Niblock,
Tim and Emma Murphy, eds. Economic
and Political Liberalization in the Middle East. British Academic Press:
London, 1993.
[9]
Sayyid,
Mustaph. "International Dimensions
of Middle Eastern Authoritarianism," in Debating Arab Authoritarianism:
Dynamics and Durability in Nondemocratic Regimes. Edited by Oliver
Schlumberger. Stanford University
Press: Stanford, 2007, 215-230.
[10]
Owen,
Ibid.
[11]
Adly,
Amr. State Reform and Development in
the Middle East: Turkey and Egypt in the Post- Liberalization Era. Rutledge: London, 2013, 70-116.
[12]
Heydemann,
Steven. 2014. “America’s Response to the Arab Uprisings: US Foreign Assistance
in an Era of Ambivalence,” Mediterranean Politics Vol. 19, 3: 299-317.
[13]
King,
Stephen. Liberalization Against
Democracy. Indiana University Press:
Indian, 2003.
[14]
Deudney,
Daniel and G. John Ikenberry. "The
Nature and Sources of International Liberal Order," Review of
International Studies, 25, 1999: 179-96.
[15]
Richards, Ibid, 57-65.
[16]
Lamy.
S.L. “Contemporary Mainstream Approaches: Neo-Realism and NeoLiberalism,” BSO, 2011:
114-129.
[17]
Khatib,
Lina. “Transforming the Media: From Tool
of the Rulers to Tool of Empowerment,” in Arab Human Development in the
Twenty-First Century: The Primacy of Empowerment, ed. Bahgat Korany. The American University in Cairo Press:
Cairo, 2014.
[18]
Lipson, Charles. “The International
Organization of Third World Debt,” in Towards a Political Economy of
Development: A Rational Choice Perspective, Edited by Robert Bates. University of California Press: Los Angeles,
1988, pg 12-46.
[19]
Richards,
Ibid, 9-20.
[20]
Richards,
Ibid, pg 100.
[21]
Adly,
Amr, Ibid.
[22]
Kadhim,
Abbas, ed. Governance in the Middle
East and North Africa. Rutledge:
London, 2013.
[23]
Kauppi,
M. and P. Viotti. “Economic
Structuralism: Global Capitalism and Postcolonialism,” VK, 2012: 187-207.
[24]
Ould-Mey,
Mohameden. "Structural Adjustment
Programs and Democratization in Africa," pg 35-66 in Multiparty
Democracy and Political Change: Constraints to Democratization in Africa. Edited by John Mukum Mbaku and Julius
Omozuanvbo Ihonvbere. Africa World
Press: New Jersey, 2006.
[25]
Richards, Ibid, 24-27.
[26]
Richards, Ibid.
[27]
Ould-Mey, Ibid.
[28]
King,
Stephen. Liberalization Against
Democracy. Indiana University Press:
Indian, 2003.
[29]
Adly, Ibid, 28-69.
No comments:
Post a Comment