Monday, June 8, 2015

Literature Review: Political Development in the Middle East

Introduction
Over the last two decades, Middle East specialists in political science and other academic fields have used a wide variety of approaches to understand problems with political and economic development in the region; in particular, the region’s apparent immunity to the wave of democratization that effected Latin America, Eastern Europe, and Sub-Saharan Africa throughout the 1980’s and 1990’s.  With the fall of the Berlin Wall and the collapse of authoritarianism in Eastern Europe, many political scientists thought it was only a matter of time before the same thing happened in the Middle East.  The field became dominated by researchers looking for any sign that the region’s political systems were opening up.  However, by the 2000’s, it became apparent that authoritarian regimes in the region were far more flexible and durable than previously thought.  Although the Arab Spring in 2011 created an initial wave of optimism in the academic community, the lack of democratic transitions in the region, perhaps with the exception of Tunisia, only reinforced the perception that the Middle East was unique in terms of its struggle to democratize.   Political scientists over the last decade have used a great variety of approaches to try and understand why this might be the case.
There is a lot to learn by comparing and contrasting the literature.  For one, researches have used a great variety of qualitative and quantitative methods to understand the region.  They have made use of the sciences of economics, anthropology, sociology, international relations, comparative politics, history, and gender studies in their works.  By approaching the problem of political and economic development from many different angles, these researchers show that there are multiple complications with development in the region, many of which are interconnected with each other.  Problems with rentierism, clientelism, Islamic radicalism, gender inequality, ethnic conflict, economic dependency on the West, environmental degradation, over population, the suppression of civil liberties, a lack of regional economic integration, and a plethora of new authoritarian maintenance strategies have created problems with governance and the political economy.  Understanding the complexity of problems with governance and democratization in the region requires a diversity of methodologies and coordination among scholars operating in different fields.
To compare and contrast the literature, I have chosen four works that represent a diverse sampling of the research completed over the last couple of decades on the issue of political development in the Middle East.  They are as follows: Governance in the Middle East and North Africa, which was edited by Abbass Kadhim; “Does Oil Hinder Democracy,” by Michael Ross; “Taming Wusta to Achieve Development,” by Robert Cunningham and Yasin Sarayrah; and “Islam and Democracy in the Middle East: The Impact of Religious Orientations on Attitudes toward Democracy in Four Arab Countries,” by Mark Tessler.  The authors of the book and the articles mentioned above make use of a diversity of different strategies to understand governance in the Middle East and the obstacles to political and economic development in the region.

Governance in the Middle East and North Africa
                Abbas Kadhim’s edited book Governance in the Middle East and North Africa, which was written in 2013, provides a diverse array of perspectives on political development in the Middle East and the challenges facing the region.[1]  Like many other scholarly works in the social sciences over the last few decades, each chapter is written by different specialists who focus on their own area of research.   Chapters one through ten focus on general issues affecting governance in the Middle East like corruption, excessive military spending, rentier states, unemployment, a lack of regional trade, radical Islamism, the suppression of civil liberties, and gender inequality.  Chapters eleven through twenty eight consist of individual country case studies where we get to see many exceptions to the general problems affecting governance in the region.  Overall, the book seeks to bring together the macro and micro as well as qualitative and quantitative studies in one exhaustive volume.  What is good about these kinds of books is that the reader has the opportunity to look at the issue of governance in the MENA region from a great diversity of perspectives and methodologies.   
Of course, the biggest drawback for the editors of these volumes is tying the research and ideas of all of the authors together to create general theories about political development.   After all, one of the main goals of political science is to explain the most phenomena while using the least amount of independent variables possible, but trying to coordinate the ideas of authors who use different methodologies and come from different academic disciplines is not easy.  The writers in Governance in the Middle East and North Africa do make frequent mention of each other throughout the book; however, with the exception of a very terse introduction, the work lacks a single voice that could truly tie together these diverse perspectives.   This does not mean that Abbas Kadhim did not attempt to synchronize the works of the various authors in the book.  He places the chapters of the book in a very specific order to show the reader how the various problems with governance and development in the region are interconnected with each other.
He purposely placed the article “Governance-constrained growth in the MENA region” by Robert Looney at the beginning of the work because it sets the stage for the book’s central question: why has the Middle East struggled with political and economic development in comparison with other regions of the world over the last half century.[2]   Before answering this question, Kadhim’s edited volume needed a comparativist like Robert Looney who could define concepts like good governance and economic growth, and who could establish how the Middle East compares with other regions of the world. 
Looney used a diverse array of statistics and indexes to make a connection between his independent and dependent variables, which are governance and economic growth respectively, in order to compare and contrast different regions of the world.  Looney feels that economic growth requires a country’s integration with the global economy; stable and sufficient tax collection; and the protection of private property, and this can only achieved through good governance.  To define governance, he relies on a complex index developed by the World Bank, which measures the following six variables using a diverse array of surveys conducted in each country: voice and accountability (civil liberties); political stability; government effectiveness; regulatory quality; rule of law; and control of corruption.  He measures economic growth with GDP per capita and the Heritage Foundation’s Economic Freedom Index.  After comparing and contrasting between regions, what he finds is that Asia and Central/Eastern Europe have had significantly higher rates of economic growth over the last half century than Latin America, the Middle East, and Sub Saharan Africa, and this is correlated with the quality of governance.  East Asia and Central Europe scored consistently higher on the World Bank’s governance indicator than the other three regions.  Although the Middle East did score slightly better than Latin America and Sub-Saharan Africa on some governance indicators like perceptions of corruption and the rule of law, they ranked at the bottom on governance indicators connected with the level of political freedom like voice and accountability.
The proceeding chapters seek to understand why the region has problems with governance and, in turn, economic growth.   Democratization, in particular, has eluded the region.  One of the facts that make the Middle East unique in comparison with the rest of the world is the presence of vast quantities of fossil fuels.  Approximately two thirds of the world’s oil reserves are located in the region.  This is why Kadhim followed up Looney’s article with Mary Ann Tetreault’s “Stuff is Not Enough: Resources and Governance in the Middle East,” which looks at the effects of rents like water, religious monuments, transport routes, and most importantly oil on governance.[3]  A lot has been written about the pernicious effects of oil on developing countries within the field of political science.  Although the resource has generated a lot of wealth for fossil fuel exporting countries in places like the Gulf, overdependence on the resource has stalled political and economic development over all.  Oil does create wealth, but it is a resource that can easily be concentrated in the hands of an authoritarian government who can then use that wealth to buy off political opponents and silence those who aren’t as easily co-opted with coercion.  Since the wealth from rents does not have to be earned, governments lack the incentive to tax their own population or invest in industry and quality educational institutions.  Furthermore, these regimes are dangerously dependent on a single resource that is neither stable nor viable for the long term future.   Even the regimes in the Middle East that don’t have large amounts of oil resources have other forms of rents like oil pipelines, strategic transportation routes, remittances from workers in the oil industry, religious/historical monuments, and access to Western aid due to the strategic importance of the region.  Rentierism is a problem that affects most of the Middle East.  This is one of the reasons why the region has struggled with political and economic development according to Tetreault.
Kathim follows up Tetreault’s article with Charles Dunbar’s “The Middle East political economy and the Arab Awakening: A Difficult symbiosis?,”  which discusses the connections between authoritarianism, poor governance, unemployment, and the revolutions of 2011.[4]  Dunbar discusses how Middle East states, following independence from Europe, created highly centralized political economies in the 1950’s with the aim of redistributing capital from agriculture to industry to modernize their countries.  Part of the rational for this is that they were protecting their economies from Western industry by placing heavy tariffs on imports; also, governments were seen as the only institutions with enough capital in underdeveloped societies to invest in industrialization.  However, these import-substitution strategies failed to achieve the desired level of growth due to numerous political factors. Due to intense social cleavages, authoritarian governments in the Middle East too often sacrificed long term economic development for short term political stability by creating expensive welfare states and distributing jobs in the bureaucracy to loyal political clients.  Bureaucracies throughout the region became heavily politicized and corrupt, creating problems with the rule of law, the infrastructure, educational systems, and foreign investment.  State controlled industries too often became inefficient and unprofitable, and debt ridden countries were forced to turn to international banks for loans.   As populations and urbanization increased, governments in the Middle East couldn’t provide enough jobs for people, and budget constraints led to the reduction of social welfare programs.   Although states in the Gulf were able to mitigate these problems due to large amounts of oil rents and small populations, other countries in the region struggled to maintain the costs of their over bloated bureaucracies.  Charles Dunbar makes the claim that discontent over the quality of governance and deteriorating economic conditions set the stage for the revolutions of 2011.
Failing to develop free markets protected by the rule of law, countries in the Middle East failed to significantly diversify their economies.  This has led to significant problems with enhancing regional trade according to Claire Brunel and Gary Hufbauer in the article “Trade agreements in the MENA region: Contribution to Better Governance,” which is the fourth chapter of the book.[5]   Brunel and Hufbauer note that increasing international trade can increase good governance since it requires developing countries to meet the regulatory standards of developed countries.  Furthermore, increased trade eases regional political tensions and allows for the sharing of technology and resources.   Although trade has increased substantially between the Middle East and the West since the 1970’s, MENA countries have not significantly increased trade with their own neighbors or strengthened regional political and economic institutions, perhaps with the exception of the Gulf Cooperation Council.   According to the author, an abundance of international institutions have been created within Africa and the Middle East for the purposes of promoting greater regional and sub-regional trade, but there are many political and economic road blocks standing in the way of reform.  Since authoritarian regimes fear that competition and legal reforms will weaken their base of power in their own countries, they are hesitant to allow imports that are free of some kind of formal or informal tax in order to protect domestic businesses loyal to the regime.  These problems with international trade have played a role in reducing the effectiveness of governance throughout the region.
Problems with economic and political development have, in turn, led to growing political discontent in the Middle East over the last few decades and the rise of Islamist opposition movements.   Much has been written on this subject as Islamist social movements have created numerous complications with governance in the region.  Mohammed M. Hafez discusses the nature of these Islamist movements in an article titled “Illegitimate governance: The roots of Islamist radicalization in the MENA” in chapter five.[6]  According to Hafez, these Islamist movements share a lot in common.  They all seek to mix religion and state.  Furthermore, most of these groups view the governments that oppress them as being corrupt and adjust; according to them, only Islam can provide the moral solution necessary to address the political, economic, and social evils created by secular, authoritarian rule.  However, according to Hafez, Islamism as a growing social movement has manifested itself in a number of different ways.  Some of these groups are more passive, preferring to partially cooperate with ruling regimes in exchange for being allowed to establish their charitable organizations and social networks.  Several authoritarian regimes, like in Egypt from the 1970’s to the 2000’s, allowed Islamist networks like the Muslim Brotherhood to operate as they provided much needed social welfare that the government was increasingly unable to provide.  Many of these Islamist networks have been provided with a lot of funding through remittances from laborers in wealthy Gulf countries.  Other Islamist movements have instead turned to violence as the main solution to overthrow repressive governments.  Authoritarian regimes have often responded with coercion to suppress these movements.  
The rises of Islamist movements have created numerous problems with governance.  Other than increasing the potential for political conflict, it also led to the establishment of more conservative social norms, causing problems with women’s rights.  In Chapter 8, Vickie Langohr and Amaney Jamal discuss this issue in the article “The improvement of women’s rights in the Arab world.”[7]  Although the status of women in terms of unemployment and education has improved considerably in the last few decades, the Middle East still ranks last in all major categories that measure women’s empowerment; this has created a major obstacle to political and economic development.  The positive reforms that have been enacted in the region to deal with issues like underrepresentation of females in parliament and access to jobs for women have almost all taken place as a result of authoritarian leaders forcing reforms on the rest of society.  Monarchs and presidents alike that have attempted reform were resisted heavily by conservative social forces resisting change.   Many Western political scientists have debated whether or not these Islamist social and political movements constitute civil society since much of their rhetoric is anti-democratic and often discriminatory towards females and religious minorities.   
While authoritarian regimes have faced a lot of pressure from below, they have also faced pressure from Western countries and minorities within their own countries that support liberal, democratic reform.  Since the 1970’s, authoritarian regimes throughout the regime that have sought Western aid and loans have often been pressured to introduce democratic institutions and allow a space for non-governmental organizations to operate.  Heather S. Gregg writes about this in “The prospects for democratization in the Middle East” in chapter seven.[8]   Authoritarian regimes all eventually responded to these international pressures with superficial democratic reforms, creating parliaments that have little power and fraudulent elections with predetermined outcomes.   Gregg doubts that these new institutions will lead to real democratization in the near future.  If anything, many authors have argued that these fake institutions only reinforce authoritarianism as they provide a way for these regimes to increase their legitimacy and co-opt oppositional movements without actually allowing real political competition.
                However, as political and economic problems have grown throughout the region over the last four decades, authoritarian regimes have had greater difficulty making the necessary adjustments to avoid political unrest, labor strikes, revolutions, and calls for democratization.   As the world becomes more interconnected due to the internet and digital technology, it will become more difficult for regimes to suppress the rising expectations of their people who will want better governance and accountability.  Aqeel Abood writes in “Revolutions in the Middle East: Demands for political, social, and economic changes and the states’ repressive response” in chapter ten:
The Middle Eastern revolutions have no doubt taught us many valuable lessons.  The movements of the youth in Tunisia, Egypt, Libya, Bahrain, and elsewhere have proven, first, that fear of the state neither plays a key factor in driving people to do things, nor is influential from the state’s point of view as a key factor in shaping people’s social, political, and economic fates.”[9]

Regimes in the region are now caught between social groups calling for liberal and Islamist reforms; they are also facing the difficult challenge of choosing between economic policies that promote short term political stability or long term economic development.  They face these difficult challenges while dealing with growing populations, diminishing resources, environmental degradation, and rising expectations for better governance among their population. 
                Of course, each country in the MENA region is facing its own unique challenges.  Chapters eleven through twenty year discuss problems with governance in each state.[10]  Some countries have had it worse than others.  For example, Lebanon has the unique challenge of dealing with a sectarian political system where eighteen different ethnic groups have to coexist within a small state.  Iraq is dealing with the legacy of Saddam Hussein, the US occupation, and sectarian warfare between religion and ethnic groups.  Resource poor Yemen has had to deal with tribal, religious, and geographic social cleavages that have frequently led to the civil war in the country over the last few decades.  Palestinians have had to live with the reality of Israeli occupation since 1967.  Syria experienced forty years of highly oppressive authoritarian rule where an Alawite minority dominated over a Sunni majority, and a subsequent civil war that has claimed the lives of over 200,000 individuals.  On the other hand, some countries have been more fortunate.  The Arab Gulf has the luxury of having small populations and enormous oil wealth, allowing governments to provide their citizens with a lavish lifestyle.  Turkey, a unique outlier in the region, has been able to sideline its military from politics, diversify its economy, and establish a more pluralistic form of government in the last few decades.  There are also countries that have a mixed situation.  Egypt, Morocco, Jordan, and Tunisia have experienced far more stability than their conflict ridden neighbors, but they suffer from stagnant authoritarian political systems where stability is traded for long term economic development.  Tunisia is the only country that currently has the potential to transform into a pluralistic, democratic society following its revolution in 2011.   These chapters in Khadim’s book highlight the fact that there is a great amount of diversity in the region.
There are of course some problematic issues with some of the main conclusions of the book.  One of the problems with the opening chapter and the book in general is that its definition of economic development is tied very closely with the Washington Consensus and politically partisan, right wing organizations that promote it like the Heritage Foundation.  These organizations promote a neoliberal view of international relations, which seeks to promote free trade and democracy throughout the world.  For these groups, economic growth and political stability is what matters; issues like equality, the environment, health, and education are secondary. 
Even though GDP per capita can tell us about the total wealth produced by a country, it cannot tell us about the degree of economic inequality or the level of human development as measured by variables like health and education.   Furthermore, although economic integration with the rest of the globe does create greater access to new technology, markets, and information, it also means that developing markets might get flooded with cheaply produced goods, making it more difficult to establish a local industrial sector.  This is not to imply that the authors in this book do not acknowledge these issues at various points or do not address issues like education; however, several of the authors in the book see economic growth and integration with the global economy purely as signs of political and economic progress.  The fact that the main topics of the first half of the book focus on Washington Consensus issues like international trade agreements, employment, and security while issues like education, the environment, and poverty are not main topics is indicative of most of the authors’ views on development in the region.

Does Oil Hinder Democracy?
                Over the last couple of decades, there has been a plethora of journal articles written on political development in the Middle East; one of the most popular topics is the issue of oil rents and its effect on political development and democratization.  Michael Ross, in an article titled “Does Oil Hinder Democracy,” relies on complex quantitative methods to compare and contrast regimes that are highly dependent on oil and mineral resource rents with those that are not.  The purpose of doing so was to understand what affect rents have on political development and why rentierism impedes democratization.[11]    The study trades quantity for quality by using a large amount of statistics to compare 113 states over a twenty four year period to see if there is a negative correlation between rentierism and democratization.
The most impressive aspect about Ross’ methodology is the way in which he compares massive amounts of statistics over a long period of time, and the creative ways he operationalizes his variables.  He measured rentierism on a graduated scale based on what percentage of government expenditures is dependent on oil and mineral resources.  Furthermore, he measured his dependent variable, democratization, on a scale of zero to ten, using many of the same standards currently put to use by Freedom House and other international institutions.   He did far more than compare the data to see if there is a correlation between the independent and dependent variables; the author also analyzed the statistics to see if non-rentier states progressed faster politically than rentier states from 1973 to 1977.  He used computer software to analyze what would happen if variables like Islamic countries or Gulf countries were removed from the analysis; individual regions were also analyzed to see if rentierism had a different affect on governance in these parts of the world.   What he found was that there was a correlation between rentierism and struggles with democratization irrespective of other variables like culture, religion, or the time period being studied. 
To understand why, Ross compared the 113 countries to see if rentier states were more likely to have low levels of taxation; spend more on state welfare and defense; and have less economic diversity.   The results showed a clear correlation between rentierism and low tax rates as well as high spending on government welfare; however, results were far less clear in terms of the rentier state’s connection with increased spending on security and the lack of diversity in the economy.  The author feels that more research is needed in this area to understand why rentierism seems to impede democratization.
Of course, the weakness in the study is that it is broad and does not go into the specific details of each country.  There might be other factors that are impeding democratization in rentier states outside of an overdependence on oil and mineral resources.  We would need more case studies over a much longer period of time to be sure of Michael Ross’ findings.  The author admits this and knows that more research needs to be completed in the future.

Taming Wusta to Achieve Development
                Another major problem that impedes development in the region is clientelism, which refers to vertical social networks where patrons give benefits to clients in exchange for loyalty.  Robert Cunningham and Yasin Sarayrah discuss this topic in the article “Taming Wusta to Achieve Development,” showing how clientelism leads to corruption in bureaucracies, which in turn leads to problems with the rule of law.[12]   Unlike Michael Ross, these authors relied on qualitative methods to understand the connection between the independent and dependent variables.
                To understand the pernicious effects of clientelism, Cunningham and Sarayrah describe the stories of several individuals who obtained jobs in the Jordanian bureaucracy through nepotism.  Through these case studies, the authors show how these clientele networks discourage hard work since gaining jobs is based on connections and not qualifications.  Furthermore, once a person gets a job, their position is only secure as long as their patron remains in a position of power, creating a great degree of uncertainty.  To make matters worse, the person with the connection is than pressured by family members and friends to use his position of power to help out his relatives while he still can.   Even if the bureaucrat wants to do his job properly, there are social forces acting upon him that make it nearly impossible.  Also, the bureaucrat’s boss has less room to discipline his worker for bad behavior.  The end result is that bureaucrats end up performing poorly, eating up state resources while little is accomplished.  Through the micro-study, we can understand the complex dynamics of individual patron-client networks and how they negatively affect governance.
                There are several weaknesses in the methodology used by the authors.  Although the individual stories help the reader understand how cliental networks function, we have no idea how common this phenomenon is in Jordan or the rest of the Middle East in general based on this study alone.  Furthermore, the causes of it are vaguely attributed to oil rents and the influence of Bedouin culture.  Even more problematic is the author’s proposed solution to the problem.  The authors suggest that managers can deal with bad employees in a cliental system by following the Bedouin tradition of sitting down with all of the parties involved in the social network and discussing the performance of the worker in question over a cup of tea.  Cunningham and Sarayrah offer no case examples of companies who had success implementing this strategy.  To be fair to the authors, clientelism, unlike state rents, is not an easy phenomenon to quantify; the relations between patron and client are informal after all.  We can only quantify variables that are indirectly connected to clientelism like worker efficiency. 
 
Islam and Democracy in the Middle East
                Another common variable that is linked to problems with democratization is the influence of Islamic culture on the region.  Mark Tessler, in “Islam and Democracy in the Middle East,” hypothesized that the Middle East had generally negative attitudes towards democracy in the 1970’s and 1980’s due to conservative religious attitudes.[13] To test his hypothesis, he completed surveys in four countries throughout the MENA region, including Algeria, Morocco, Egypt, and Palestine.  The surveys attempted to quantify religious beliefs and political attitudes to determine if negative attitudes towards democracy were correlated with religious belief.  Although he confirmed that there was a generally negative attitude towards democracy, its connection with Islamic beliefs was inconclusive.
                There were several problems with this study.   First of all, he didn’t ask Muslims living outside the region to see if people of the same faith living within different political environments held different perspectives on democracy.   Furthermore, he didn’t give the same surveys to people of different faiths living in other autocratic governments.  Lastly, he wasn’t able to give surveys in Egypt, Morocco, and Algeria outside of the major cities, which means that he was not able to sample the full population.   One of the obstacles facing Middle East regional specialists is the difficulty of using surveys to measure popular opinions.  Authoritarian regimes place a lot of restrictions on academics in this area.  Although Tessler’s hypothesis is relevant, testing it is very difficult in a region that lacks basic civil liberties.   



Conclusion
                Although there is a growing base of diverse of literature on political and economic development in the Middle East, there is a lot of work that needs to be done to improve the methodologies we use to study variables in the region.  Also, many research topics need further study.  Following the 2011 revolutions that caught the academic community by surprise, it is obvious that much more needs to be done in terms of understanding political development in the region.



Work Cited
1. Cunningham, Robert and Yasin Sarayrah. 1995. “Taming Wasta to Achieve Development,” Arab Studies Quarterly, Vol. 16, 3: 29-41.
2. Kadhim, Abbas, ed.  Governance in the Middle East and North Africa.  Routledge: 2013.
3. Ross, Michael. "Does oil hinder democracy?" World Politics, 53 (3): 325-361.
4. Tessler, Mark.  "Islam and Democracy in the Middle East: The Impact of Religious Orientations on Attitudes toward Democracy in Four Arab Countries," Comparative Politics, Vol. 34, No. 3 (Apr., 2002), pp. 337-354.




[1] Kadhim, Abbas, ed.  Governance in the Middle East and North Africa.  Routledge: 2013.
[2] Ibid, 3-32.
[3] Ibid, 33-46.
[4] Ibid, 50-62.
[5] Ibid, 63-84.
[6] Ibid, 85-97.
[7] Ibid, 133-154.
[8] Ibid, 112-132.
[9] Ibid, 182.
[10] Ibid,
[11] Ross, Michael. "Does oil hinder democracy?" World Politics, 53 (3): 325-361.
[12] Cunningham, Robert and Yasin Sarayrah. 1995. “Taming Wasta to Achieve Development,” Arab Studies Quarterly, Vol. 16, 3: 29-41.
[13] Tessler, Mark.  "Islam and Democracy in the Middle East: The Impact of Religious Orientations on Attitudes toward Democracy in Four Arab Countries," Comparative Politics, Vol. 34, No. 3 (Apr., 2002), pp. 337-354.

No comments:

Post a Comment