Sunday, March 4, 2018

Special Interests and America's Political System


Introduction
            The nineteenth century intellectual Alexis de Tocqueville, in his classic work Democracy in America, claimed that “In no country in the world has the principle of association been more successfully used, or more sparingly applied to a multitude of objects, than in America” (Tocqueville, 213). Comparative specialists continue to see the United States as an oddity among developed nations due to the great diversity of interest groups that have been able to influence the country’s presidential political system with its many veto points (Steinmo, 2003). However, most scholars today are not as optimistic as Tocqueville was on the subject and with good reason. Over the last half century, the amount of money interest groups have spent on media access and campaign financing has grown substantially. According to Celestine Bohlen of the New York Times, “In 2016, candidates running for office spent a record $6.4 billion on their campaigns, while lobbyists spent $3.15 billion to influence the government in Washington.”[1] These organizations now represent a diversity of special interests including those of businesses, labor unions, professional syndicates, and civil rights activists. Through their lobbying efforts and investment in think tanks, they have shaped the development of public policy on important issues such as taxation (Steinmo, 1989), the budget deficit (Schick, 1993), and healthcare (Hacker, 1998). While this much is agreed upon in the American political science community, there is a vigorous debate over how to define interest groups, explain their origins, and determine the precise impact that these organizations have had on the political system, the media, and public policy.
             To answer these important questions, I will analyze the literature on the topic. Numerous articles focus on the debate over the origins of interest groups. The scholars of these articles all discuss different theories on collective action and group formation, and they analyze the different socio-economic and political structures that either hinder or encourage the formation of interest groups in America. Other articles focus on interest groups as an independent variable. The scholars of these works discuss the various mechanisms by which interest groups can affect the political system and public policy. To elaborate on the different arguments on this issue, I will analyze the literature and compare their different findings. This will involve a description and critique of their research questions, literature reviews, theories, methodologies, and data results. A thorough analysis of the literature will reveal that there are several unique challenges involved with defining interest groups and measuring their impact on the political system and society.

Part One: Interest Groups as the Dependent Variable
            Jack Walker, in his 1983 article “The Origins and Maintenance of Interest Groups in America,” asks the following questions: what explains the formation of interest groups and why has their influence grown in America over the last century (Walker, 1983)?  He defines interest groups as “all the voluntary organizations in the United States which are open to membership and are concerned with some aspects of public policy at the national level.” (Walker, 391) Organizations where membership is non-voluntary, such as unions and businesses, are left out of his study as are groups that do not attempt to lobby the national government. He also divides interest groups into two categories: professional syndicates open only to members of that profession, and citizen groups that have open membership for all Americans. Based on this conceptualization of the term, the number of interest groups lobbying the government grew from approximately 500 in 1929 to 1,700 in 1980 with the greatest expansion taking place during the civil rights movement in the 1960’s.
            What explains the exponential growth in the number of interest groups in the middle of the twentieth century? To answer this question, Walker starts his analysis with a literature view. Over the prior three decades, scholars in American political science had debated the reasons for the formation of interest groups. In the 1950’s, professors such as David Truman argued that organizations spontaneously formed in response to socioeconomic and political problems that emerged in society. Once a set of groups formed, this would cause other actors in society to respond by forming their own organizations in opposition to protect their own interests. For this reason, Truman’s theory is a highly egalitarian and pluralistic conception of civil society. However, it did not take long for other scholars to criticize this theory. By the mid-1960’s, academics such as Mancur Olson argued from a rational choice perspective that the formation of interest groups was not an egalitarian process. Forming an organization to lobby the government requires financial resources, time, and skills that are not readily available to most citizens. Interest groups require a consistent source of funding and a staff of qualified workers if they are to survive. Consequently, it is not a rational choice for most individuals to form a group or even participate in one. Instead, interest group formation is determined by elites with capital and access to or control over preexisting organizations.
            To reconcile the differences in the literature, Walker conducted an inductive large n-study to analyze the development of interest groups in America. He argues that previous studies on interest groups only analyzed the development of a small number of organizations that confirmed their theories, so a broader study of organizations was required. To understand the origin of groups, he mailed out a little over 900 questionnaires to approximately 900 interest groups, and about 500 were filled out and returned. Questions were asked on the origins of the group, the requirements of membership, sources of funding, and lobbying activities. The results of these questionnaires partly conform to Truman’s theory. The data shows that the formation of most interest groups happened in response to sociopolitical and economic problems at critical junctures in history. Some of these interest groups were professional syndicates and chambers of commerce that formed in response to the industrial revolution in the late nineteenth century. Disputes over wages, working conditions, and technical training led blue collar workers, professionals, and businessmen to join professional syndicates voluntarily in the hopes that collective action through lobbying would lead to long term benefits. Other groups formed in the aftermath of Franklin Roosevelt’s New Deal in the 1930’s and the expansion of the federal bureaucracy. For example, citizen organizations like the American Association of Retired Workers (AARP) defended the Social Security benefits of the elderly against attacks from those who wanted to retrench the welfare state. Finally, many groups formed in response to the Vietnam War and the civil rights movement in the 1950’s and 1960’s to defend the rights of African Americans, Native Americans, women, and veterans.
            However, Walker’s data also partially conforms to Mancur Olson’s rational-choice theory. 85 percent of interest groups that still existed by 1983 were not citizens groups with open membership for all people but closed professional syndicates in the public and private sector.  It was easier for these groups to form and survive due to access to funding from private sector businesses, unions, and the government. Furthermore, most of these professional syndicates were formed by preexisting public and private organizations. The government and wealthy patrons have played a disproportionate role in the creation and financing of these organizations. According to Walker, over half of the interest groups in 1983 were also started after WWII, and this can partially be explained by the fast rate of economic growth in America after the war, the growing number of college educated professionals, and the ease of communication and transport due to changes in technology. Through his analysis of the data, Walker forms a theory of interest group formation that borrows from both Truman’s and Olsen’s theoretical frameworks. Interest groups due form in response to socio-economic problems but elites have a disproportionate influence over their formation and survival.
            While Walker’s analysis provides some explanations for the formation and growth of interest groups, there are several problems with the internal validity of Walker’s methodology. His exclusion of labor unions as interest groups—despite their extensive donations to campaigns and their extensive lobbying efforts over the last century (Wilcox, 1988)—is a questionable decision. Labor unions were arguably the most important form of organization for blue collar workers in late nineteenth and early twentieth century America. While they often used coercion to force their members to join, excluding them from the typology of interest groups may exaggerate the influence of financial resources and preexisting organizations on the development of interest groups in America. This would affect the internal validity of the study. Does an organization need to have only voluntary membership to be an interest group? Moreover, including only organizations that lobby the national government excludes local and state level interest groups that do not require as much funding or support to survive. To be an interest group, does an organization have to lobby the national government, or can they also form in response to problems in local communities? Many citizens are concerned with purely local issues such as the condition of schools, taxes, or infrastructure. By excluding small and local organizations from his analysis, does this create a less egalitarian picture of American society?
            Furthermore, since Walker’s focus is on long term socioeconomic trends that affect interest group formation, his analysis ignores the short term impact of electoral politics on interest group formation. Jack Wilcox, in the 1988 article “PAC’s and Pluralism: Interest Group Formation and Partisanship,” analyzes the effects of election results on the formation of Political Action Committees from the 1970’s to the 1980’s (Wilcox, 1988). According to Wilcox, “In the decade from 1974 to 1984, the number of PAC organizations grew from 600 to well over 4,000,” and the influence of corporations on the political system through campaign financing grew while unions declined (Wilcox, 156). Once again, the theories of both Olsen and Truman add to our understanding of what might be happening. In confirmation of Olsen’s theory, access to resources explains why certain organizations such as corporations were able to donate more money to the formation of PAC’s than unions in each election year. However, this does not explain the yearly fluctuations in donations for partisan PAC’s that are supporting either Democratic or Republican candidates or the creation of new partisan PAC’s. Wilcox adds another explanatory variable to explain what is happening. In line with Truman’s thinking about interest group formation, Wilcox theorized that the victory of one political party in an election will lead to political entrepreneurs in the opposition to use their defeat as a way to raise more money and create new PAC’s. An electoral loss will provide motivation to both political leaders and the rank-and-file supporters of the losing political party to donate more money to the interest groups they support and to form new interest groups. This will lead to the escalation of money spent on campaign financing over time as political parties compete to win elections.
            To test this theory, Wilcox analyzes the formation of PAC’s and campaign financing from 1977 to 1984. He uses data from the Federal Election Commission to analyze which interest groups gave resources to which PAC’s, and whether these PAC’s gave to Republican or Democratic candidates in Congressional House races. Four major types of interest groups are identified as funders of PACS: corporations, unions, trade organizations, and non-connected PAC’s that are ideological in nature. He analyzes the donations of PAC’s to politicians from the majority and minority parties after each congressional and presidential election. Wilcox controlled for whether PAC’s were giving to incumbents or challengers to make sure that PAC’s were not only donating money to safe incumbent candidates but were in fact donating money to both incumbents and challengers in response to a previous electoral defeat. The results confirmed his analysis: the amount of money given to PAC’s and the formation of new PAC’s is correlated with a partisan response to electoral defeats in the previous election cycle.
            While this theory goes a long way towards explaining why opposition movements are often quick to mobilize after their party’s electoral defeat, there are problems with the external validity of Wilcox’s study. The theory assumes that there is an unlimited amount of resources and no political structures that could potentially limit growth in the size or number of PACS. It is possible that the trend of escalation in campaign financing spending could hit a ceiling if one or both parties maximize the resources that are available or if the government decides to regulate PAC behavior. Furthermore, the growth in the number of PAC’s may come to a halt if the population ecology in which interest groups operate becomes saturated with older PAC’s to the point where new organizations find it difficult to raise money.
            Anthony Nownes, in the article “The Population Ecology of Interest Group Formation: Mobilizing for Gay and Lesbian Rights in the United States, 1950-98,” addresses these issues (Nownes, 2004). In the article, he analyzes the reasons why gay rights organizations grew in number from 1950 to 1980, declined in the 1980’s, grew again in the early 1990’s, and plateaued by the late 1990’s.  Part of Nownes theoretical framework borrows from the research of David Meyer and Douglas Imig, who showed that political institutions can either incentivize or block the formation of new interest groups depending on the social and political context. Initially, gay rights organizations struggled to grow in the 1950’s due to political oppression by the state and the lack of acceptance in society. However, the civil rights movement provided a more open space and greater legitimacy for gay rights activists to operate, raise money, and form institutions. A critical juncture in the gay rights movement was the Stone Wall riots of 1969, which led to growing sympathy for homosexuals in America. Joining an organization became less risky politically. The fortunes of gay rights organizations temporarily turned when the AID’s epidemic and Ronald Reagan’s presidency led to a backlash against the gay rights movement and the rise of interest groups supported by evangelical churches. The growth rate in gay rights groups declined. This changed once again during the presidency of Bill Clinton as the AID’s epidemic became a less salient issue and the acceptance of gays in American culture continued to improve. This led to further growth in the number of groups. However, by the end of the 1990’s, the growth rate in the number of groups slowed down and the total number of groups started to plateau for reasons unrelated to political institutions, socioeconomics, or culture. Why was this case? To explain this, Nownes borrows from theories on the ecology of group formation and density dependence.  While certain political and socio economic conditions can lead to the growth in the number of groups, society will eventually become saturated with these groups, leaving no further room for growth. Due to more intense competition, older groups will prevent newer and smaller groups from forming.
            To test this theory, Nownes measured the growth of homosexual rights organizations from 1950 to 1998. His hypothesis was that the growth rate of interest groups would have a “u-shape” since group formation would first accelerate than slow down and plateau. To operationalize the dependent variable, which is the growth rate in the number of new groups per year, he used the Encyclopedia of Associations and the indexes of the New York Times throughout this time period to identify when new groups formed. To measure the independent variable, which is organizational density, he measured the total amount of organizations that were still active at the beginning of each year. He controlled for the political openness of the system based on the amount of congressional hearings held on homosexuality each year, the amount of stories a year that were discussed on homosexuality in the New York Times, and the amount of Democrats in congress. A dummy variable was also added for Bill Clinton’s presidency since he was more outspoken in his support of the gay community than past presidents. Nownes also controlled for time periods, which includes the years before and after the Stone Wall riots and the years during the Reagan and Clinton Presidencies. The results of the multi regression analysis confirmed Nownes’ theory. During the 1950’s and 1960’s, the degree of political openness was a statistically significant variable that explained the growth of gay rights organizations. However, as the density of gay rights organizations increased, the degree of openness became less and less of a factor. By the 1990’s, the degree of openness did not matter at all due to the saturation of interest groups.
            While Nownes’ theoretical framework provides convincing evidence to explain the rise and plateauing of certain types of interest groups, there are some problems with the internal validity of the study. While group density may be explaining some of the reduction in the number of new homosexual groups per year after an initial period of growth, Nownes is neglecting the fact that individuals may have less incentives to lobby the government as they gained more personal rights. Truman claimed that interest groups tend to form in response to a socioeconomic or political crisis, so this would mean that there would be less incentives to form a new group during a period where there is no crisis. As homosexuals have gained the right to serve in the military, get married, and adopt children, would the next generation of homosexuals be as enthusiastic about forming new groups to protect their interests?  There may be factors other than group density at work here. Furthermore, Truman does not consider the fact that as gays gained more popular acceptance in society, more main stream organizations such as the Democratic Party began to adopt their cause. If more powerful interest groups are supporting your cause, is it as necessary to form new interest groups?


Interest Groups as the Independent Variable
            While there are disagreements over the nature of interest groups and the variables that affect their formation, there is a consensus that interest groups grew rapidly in the middle of the twentieth century and continue to have a substantial influence on the political system. However, determining the exact nature of their influence on the political system is not easy. John Wright, in the 1990 article “Contributions, Lobbying, and Committee Voting in the US House of Representatives,” struggles with this task (Wright, 1990). He asks the following research questions: do interest group lobbyists affect the outcome of public policy, and are the effects of lobbying on public policy independent of the effects of campaign financing?  According to Wright, lobbying is a very important function of interest groups that also donate money to PAC’s. Approximately 68 percent of groups that give to PAC’s also have lobbying arms. Wright is not only interested in the relationship between lobbying and public policy but lobbying and campaign financing. Does campaign financing buy votes or does it only buy lobbyists more time to influence congressmen in face-to-face meetings?
            To answer these questions, Wright first conducted a literature review. According to Wright, scholars in the 1950’s such as David Truman felt that lobbyists played the role of swaying congressmen to vote a certain way on issues by funding the campaigns of congressmen and sending lobbyists to Washington. However, this view of lobbyists began to be challenged in the 1960’s by scholars such as Lester Milbrath. Using inferential statistics, their studies revealed that lobbyists do not really change the minds of politicians but only reinforce their preexisting beliefs by supplying them with more information. In other words, once interest groups help politicians get elected through campaign financing, the goal of lobbyists is to help politicians follow through on public policy. According to this theory, interest groups have been shown to play a large role in helping the politicians they support defend their public policy stances and even help them write legislative bills, but lobbyists do not actually sway the opinions of the opposition. By the late 1970’s and 1980’s, opinions on the efficacy of lobbying began to change once again as the rate of campaign financing skyrocketed. Some political scientists found that lobbyists were able to sway a few congressmen who were on the margins in the event of close vote in committee or on the floor of congress. Other scholars found that lobbyists were more affective at swaying congressmen on certain policy issues but less effective on other issues depending on the nature of a congressmen’s constituents and the nature of the bill being debated. In electoral districts where constituents have very low levels of knowledge on an issue and are poorly organized, lobbyists were shown to be more effective at swaying congressmen. In other words, lobbyists can sway the vote on a legislative bill but only under certain circumstances. Which of these theories on lobbyists is correct?
            To test these theories, Wright analyzed the effect of lobbyists on politicians in the House of Representatives during the 99th Congress in 1985. He chose two bills from two legislative committees to analyze. The first case study was from the Ways and Means Committee, which is the most powerful and the most heavily lobbied committee in Congress since it deals with taxation. The second case study was from the Agricultural Committee, which is a more specialized committee dealing with issues that affect a far smaller number of interest groups. In the Ways and Means Committee, Wright studied the debate over a bill that would create a new tax to pay for the cleanup of hazardous waste created by fossil fuel and chemical companies. While fossil fuel and chemical companies wanted to spread out the burden of paying for clean ups across the entire business community, other business interests wanted chemical and oil companies to pay for it out of their own profits. Meanwhile, the bill in the Agricultural Committee was a far more complicated piece of legislation that would pay farmers subsidies in exchange for growing less food. Wright chose these two bills because it was very clear as to which interest groups were for and against them. Furthermore, Wright’s analysis of major newspapers in 1985 revealed that there was almost no media coverage of these issues, which would give lobbyists more influence on the congressmen in the committees. The author wanted to know the impacts that these interest groups had on politicians in these committees through lobbying and campaign financing. Furthermore, he wanted to know whether campaign financing affected who interest groups lobbied.
            The independent variable is the degree to which interest groups lobbied each congressmen in committee. To measure this, Wright first used a publication called “Washington Representatives” to gather information on the committee hearings. He was able to create a list with over 300 potential interest groups that would have an interest in the bills. He then sent out a long questionnaire to each of these groups, and 97 organizations completed it. Using these questionnaires, Wright gathered information on the positions taken by each group on the issue, the size of each lobbying group, the congressmen with whom they spoke, and the reasons for their lobbying efforts. From this information, he was able to discern which lobbyists were influencing each congressmen in committee and how many were doing it.  Wright also used the FEC’s data to measure how much money each interest group was giving each congressmen. Since congressmen can be swayed to vote by a number of factors, Wright added in a number of control variables including the ideology and party of the congressmen, whether their constituents were affected directly by the bill, the amount of campaign financing given to the congressmen, and whether the congressmen was a leader of a committee or subcommittee.  The dependent variable is how the congressmen voted. There were a total of five substantial votes in these two committees on the two bills.
            The results of the multi regression analysis showed that lobbyists have a statistically significant impact on voting. However, lobbyists have a lot to contend with in congress, including the ideology and party of the congressmen as well as the nature of the constituents, each of which has a much stronger impact on congressional votes in comparison with lobbying. Furthermore, it is more difficult for individual lobbyists to affect Congressmen in the Ways and Means committee due to the intense competition for access to the committee, whereas it was easier for lobbyists to affect congressmen in the agricultural committee where the number of lobbyists was smaller. In other words, the committee that lobbyists try to influence matters. Lastly, campaign financing did influence voting but only if interest groups used campaign financing as a way to get more time to lobby congressmen. Those groups that gave money but did not lobby had little effect on congressmen.
            While Wright’s study is impressive in terms of the complexity of the theoretical framework and the methodology that was used to study the connections between the independent and dependent variables, there are a number of problems with the internal and external validity of the study. The internal validity of the study is affected negatively by the author’s methodology. Through the use of questionnaires, Wright is assuming that lobbyists are being honest about their dealings with congressmen. It is very possible that lobbyists for chemical and fossil fuel companies might not be upfront about their efforts to influence congressmen to spend less public resources on cleaning up hazardous waste. Another problem with internal validity is that Wright assumes that the ratio of Republicans to Democrats in Congress is not correlated with interest group influence. Party identification might strongly influence how politicians vote, but interest groups also have a strong interest in supporting certain political parties over others during the election cycle. The results of Wright’s analysis may be downplaying the influence of interest groups on Congress as a result. This study also has problems with external validity. How would lobbyists fare in terms of influencing congressmen who were sitting on other committees or voting on other bills? Furthermore, would the influence of lobbyists change from year to year? Since only two bills were chosen for the study, it means that the results of the analysis might not be applicable to other times and places. To be fair to Wright, an incredible amount of data collection went into understanding the effect of lobbying on only these two bills. Studying the precise impact of lobbyists on public policy formation is a complicated and time consuming task.
            Furthermore, Wright’s study deals with two bills that are not salient to the public; what about issues that are important to the public? With salient issues, interest groups may attempt to sway congressmen indirectly through the media by changing public perceptions of an issue. Christopher Cooper, Anthony Nownes, and Martin Johnson, in the article “Interest Groups and Journalists in the United States,” analyze the relationship between interest groups and the media (Cooper, Nownes, and Johnson, 2007).  According to these authors, past studies on this subject have shown that interest groups commonly use their access to journalists and the media as a way to spread their message to the public and indirectly influence congressmen. Furthermore, many journalists have developed close ties with interest groups as they can be a source of government news. Cooper, Nownes, and Johnson ask the following research questions: to what extent do interest groups have contacts with media outlets, to what extant are interest groups an important source of news for reporters, and is the relationship symbiotic?
            To answer these questions, the authors analyzed the relationship between interest groups and media in all fifty state governments. They offer several theories to explain the different types of relationship interest groups may have with the media. In states where interest group density is very high or very low, there is a greater chance of interest group death. In high density situations, there is a lot of competition for access to politicians, and in low density situations, interest groups struggle to find the resources to survive either due to a lack of popular support or political restrictions on their activities. Therefore, in very high or very low density situations, interest groups are more likely to try to use the media to further their agenda out of desperation. As interest groups grow more powerful by establishing direct connections with politicians, they will need the media less. This happens more in states with medium interest group density. To measure interest group density per state, they measured the amount of interest groups that lobby state governments as a percentage of the population. Furthermore, journalists are less likely to need access to interest groups for news in states that have higher levels of professionalism in the government.  More professional politicians and staff means easier access to state government officials for media outlets. To measure the levels of professionalism of state governments, the authors used James King’s index, which King created in 2000.
            To measure the independent variable, which is the intensity of the relationship between interest groups and the media in each state, they sent out questionnaires to 489 journalists who specialized in covering state level politics in the year 2003. Approximately 130 of the journalists from 42 of the states completed the surveys.  They asked them questions on whether they relied on interest groups for access to information, and they were asked to rank the relative importance of interest groups as a source of information from a list of 16 potential news sources.  The great majority of journalists claimed that they did rely on interest groups as an important source of information. Furthermore, the lobbyists of interest groups and journalists do approach each other frequently although lobbyists are more likely to approach journalists. Furthermore, only a small minority of journalists report lobbyists asking them to directly change the way a story is reported to frame it better for the interest group. Cooper, Nownes, and Johnson took the results of the data and created an index to measure the intensity of the connection between journalists and interest groups in each state. Afterwards, they compared this index with the following independent variables: interest group density per state and the state’s level of government professionalism. They found that interest groups were more likely to use the media to spread their message in states with very high and very low density of interest groups. In other words, states where interest groups were weaker were more likely to develop stronger ties to the media. In addition, journalists in states that had higher levels of government professionalism were less likely to seek out interest groups for stories.
            While the results of this study show that interest groups and journalists have a significant amount of interest in courting one another, the methodology suffers from some of the same problems with internal validity as Wright’s study. We are dependent on the honesty of journalists to be fully open about their relationship with interest groups. The fact that only one third of journalists even responded to the study leads to the question of whether a true random sample has been obtained here. In defense of their methodology, it is possible to argue that if journalists are lying about their connections, they would be far more likely to lie by deemphasizing the impact of interest groups on their reporting. While the viability of the statistics would be questionable, the statistics would still be a reliable measure of comparison between states.
            Part of the reason why interest groups may want to hide the nature of their relationship with journalists and politicians is that these groups sometimes support policies that will benefit special interests but will have a negative impact on most of the public. This is especially true of interest groups that want congressmen to retrench welfare benefits. Patrick Flavin, in the article “Campaign Finance Laws, Policy Outcomes, and Political Equality in the American States,” analyzes the effect of interest groups on welfare policies and income inequality.  While Flavin does not think that campaign financing will directly purchase the votes of congressmen, he does theorize that the money does buy more personal time with representives and gives interest groups greater opportunities to sway congressmen. The more leeway states give to interest groups to donate to campaigns, the more likely it will be that wealthy businesses will influence the formation of public policy. The result will be less money spent on welfare programs and lower taxes for businesses. Therefore, states that have stricter campaign finance laws will have a more equitable political system and lower rates of income inequality. There are three ways governments can regulate campaign financing: (1) forcing interest groups to be transparent about their lobbying activity, (2) placing a cap on the amount of money that can be donated to campaigns, and (3) public financing of campaigns.
            To test this theory, Flavin conducted an ordinary least squares regression analysis of data from 1977 to 2008 with the fifty states being his case studies. The dependent variable is changes in the amount of public spending on welfare as a percentage of the state government budget for each fiscal year.  Since his theory is testing whether campaign financing affects policies that involve economic redistribution, he also conducts a placebo test to see if campaign financing affects non-redistributive policies such as spending on state parks and highway policing. For the independent variable, he uses Jeffrey Milyo’s index to measure the degree to which states regulate campaign financing. Milyo’s scale is from one to six with six being the most restrictive of campaign finance spending. Flavin also controls for numerous variables that could also affect spending on welfare. For example, he controls for ideology by measuring the degree to which both public officials and citizens are liberal on welfare state spending. He also controls for party control of state congress and the state governorship since Democrats are more likely than Republicans to spend on welfare programs regardless of campaign finance levels. Furthermore, Flavin controls for union density, the degree of unemployment, and the amount of minorities in the state. Theoretically, governments are less likely to spend on welfare if there is a larger percentage of minority groups in the state. The regression analysis showed that campaign financing has a statistically significant impact on policies that involve economic redistribution. Furthermore, campaign financing did not affect other types of policies. Flavin also tested the mechanisms that explain the connections between the independent and dependent variables. He found that campaign finance laws did not lower the total amount of money given to campaigns, but it did lower the amount that businesses were giving to campaigns. It made campaign financing more equitable and required politicians to find different sources of financing.
            While Flavin’s study provides convincing evidence that campaign finance regulation increases welfare spending, he never attempts to make a direct connection between cuts to welfare spending and economic or political inequality. All Flavin’s study shows is that campaign finance regulation leads to more spending on welfare programs. However, does an increase in spending on welfare improve economic or political equality? It seems reasonable to assume that this may be the case, but Flavin never addresses this issue.

Conclusion
            Based on this analysis of the literature, several basic conclusions can be made. First, the number of interest groups has grown substantially since the end of World War II. The growth and survival of interest groups is effected by the political structures that limit their behavior, socioeconomic changes in society, and the resources available to citizens who are interested in lobbying the government. Furthermore, the growth of interest groups has benefited large businesses over labor unions and proponents of welfare spending as the former has greater access to resources.  Secondly, lax campaign financing laws and easy access to the media and the political system has enabled interest groups to influence the decisions made by politicians. Part of this influence is indirect through the media, and part of it is direct through campaign financing and lobbying. Thirdly, the growing influence of interest groups representing large businesses has directly led to the retrenchment of the welfare state and lower taxes on the wealthy over the last four decades. It is possible that this is contributing to the growing wealth gap in America between rich and poor. 


























Work Cited
Ashbee, Edwards. 2011. “Fiscal Policy Response to the Economic Crisis in the UK and the US,” in Terrence Casey, ed., The Legacy of the Crash.  NY:  Palgrave Macmillan.

Bachrach, Peter and Morton Baratz. 1962. “The Two Faces of Power.” American Political Science Review, 56(4): 947-52.

Bartels, Achen. 2016.  Democracy for Realists.  Princeton University Press: Princeton.

Bawn, Kathleen, Martin Cohen, David Karol, Seth Masket, Hans Noel, and John Zaller.  2012.  “A Theory of Political Parties:  Groups, Policy Demands, and Nominations in American Politics,” Perspectives on Politics, 10: 571-597.

Brady, Henry, Sidney Verba, and Kay Schlozman.  1995.  "Beyond SES:  A Resource Model of Political Participation," American Political Science Review, 89:  279-294.

Cooper, Christopher, Anthony Nownes, and Martin Johnson. Spring, 2007. "Interest Groups and Journalists in the United States," State Politics and Policy Quarterly, 7(1): 39-53.

Flavin, Patrick. March, 2015. "Campaign Finance Laws, Policy Outcomes, and Political Equality in the American States," Political Research Quarterly, 68(1): 77-88.

Hacker, Jacob. 1998. “The Historical Logic of National Health Insurance:  Structure and Sequence in the Development of British, Canadian, and US Medical Policy,” Studies in American Political Development, 12:  57-130. 

Nownes, Anthony. 2004. "The Population Ecology of Interest Group Formation: Mobilizing for Gay and Lesbian Rights in the United States, 1950-98," British Journal of Political Science, 34(1): 49-67.

Schick, Allen. 1993. "Governments versus Budget Deficits," in Do Institutions Matter? Washington, DC:  Brookings Institution.

Steinmo, Sven. 1989. “Political Institutions and Tax Policy in the United States, Sweden and Britain,” World Politics, 41: 500-535.

Steinmo, Sven. 2003. “The evolution of policy ideas: tax policy in the 20th century,” British Journal of Politics and International Relations, 5(2): 206-236.


Walker, Jack. June, 1983. “The Origins and Maintenance of Interest Groups in America,” The American Political Science Review, 77(2): 390-406.

Wilcox, Clyde. 1988. "PACs and Pluralism: Interest Group Formation and Partisanship," Polity, 21(1): 155-66.

Wright, John. 1990. "Contributions, Lobbying, and Committee Voting in the US House of Representatives," American Political Science Review, 79: 400-414.



[1] Bohlen, Celestine. September 20, 2017. “American Democracy is Drowning in Money,” https://www.nytimes.com/2017/09/20/opinion/democracy-drowning-cash.html.

No comments:

Post a Comment